ADDRESSING THE CRITICISMS OF MEAN–VARIANCE OPTIMIZATION
Last updated
Last updated
describe and evaluate the use of mean–variance optimization in asset allocation
In this section, we explore several methods for overcoming some of the potential short-comings of mean–variance optimization. Techniques that address the first two criticisms mostly take three approaches: improving the quality of inputs, constraining the optimization, and treating the efficient frontier as a statistical construct. These approaches are treated in the following three subsections.
In MVO, the composition of efficient portfolios is typically more sensitive to expected return estimates than it is to estimates of volatilities and correlations. Furthermore, expected returns are generally more difficult to estimate accurately than are volatilities and correlations. Thus, in addressing the first criticism of MVO—that outputs are highly sensitive to small changes in inputs—the reading will focus on expected return inputs. However, volatility and correlation inputs are also sources of potential error.
Reverse Optimization
Reverse optimization is a powerful tool that helps explain the implied returns associated with any portfolio. It can be used to estimate expected returns for use in a forward-looking optimization. MVO solves for optimal asset weights based on expected returns, covariances, and a risk aversion coefficient. Based on predetermined inputs, an optimizer solves for the optimal asset allocation weights. As the name implies, reverse optimization works in the opposite direction. Reverse optimization takes as its inputs a set of asset allocation weights that are assumed to be optimal and, with the additional inputs of covariances and the risk aversion coefficient, solves for expected returns. These reverse-optimized returns are sometimes referred to as implied or imputed returns.
When using reverse optimization to estimate a set of expected returns for use in a forward-looking optimization, the most common set of starting weights is the observed market-capitalization value of the assets or asset classes that form the opportunity set. The market capitalization of a given asset or asset classes should reflect the collective information of market participants. In representing the world market portfolio, the use of non-overlapping asset classes representing the majority of the world’s investable assets is most consistent with theory.
Some practitioners will find the link between reverse optimization and CAPM equilibrium elegant, while others will see it as a shortcoming. For those who truly object to the use of market-capitalization weights in estimating inputs, the mechanics of reverse optimization can work with any set of starting weights—such as those of an existing policy portfolio, the average asset allocation policy of a peer group, or a fundamental weighting scheme. For those with more minor objections, we will shortly introduce the Black–Litterman model, which allows the expression of alternative forecasts or views.
In order to apply reverse optimization, one must create a working version of the all-inclusive market portfolio based on the constituents of the opportunity set. The market size or capitalization for most of the traditional stock and bond asset classes can be easily inferred from the various indexes that are used as asset class proxies. Many broad market-capitalization-weighted indexes report that they comprise over 95% of the securities, by market capitalization, of the asset classes they are attempting to represent. lists approximate values and weights for the 12 asset classes in our opportunity set, uses the weights associated with the asset classes to form a working version of the global market portfolio, and then uses the beta of each asset relative to our working version of the global market portfolio to infer what expected returns would be if all assets were priced by the CAPM according to their market beta. We assume a risk-free rate of 2.5% and a global market risk premium of 4%. Note that expected returns are rounded to one decimal place from the more precise values shown later (in ); expected returns cannot in every case be exactly reproduced based on alone because of the approximations mentioned. Also, notice in the final row of that the weighted average return and beta of the assets are 6.5% and 1, respectively.
Exhibit 12:
Reverse-Optimization Example (Market Capitalization in £ billions)
Asset Class
Mkt Cap
Weight
Return E[Ri]
Risk-Free Rate rf
Beta βi,mkt
Market Risk Premium
UK large cap
£1,354.06
3.2%
6.62%
=
2.5%
+
1.03
(4%)
UK mid cap
£369.61
0.9%
6.92%
=
2.5%
+
1.11
(4%)
UK small cap
£108.24
0.3%
7.07%
=
2.5%
+
1.14
(4%)
US equities
£14,411.66
34.4%
7.84%
=
2.5%
+
1.33
(4%)
Europe ex UK equities
£3,640.48
8.7%
8.63%
=
2.5%
+
1.53
(4%)
Asia Pacific ex Japan equities
£1,304.81
3.1%
8.51%
=
2.5%
+
1.50
(4%)
Japan equities
£2,747.63
6.6%
6.43%
=
2.5%
+
0.98
(4%)
Emerging market equities
£2,448.60
5.9%
8.94%
=
2.5%
+
1.61
(4%)
Global REITs
£732.65
1.8%
9.04%
=
2.5%
+
1.64
(4%)
Global ex UK bonds
£13,318.58
31.8%
4.05%
=
2.5%
+
0.39
(4%)
UK bonds
£1,320.71
3.2%
2.95%
=
2.5%
+
0.112
(4%)
Cash
£83.00
0.2%
2.50%
=
2.5%
+
0.00
(4%)
£41,840.04
100.0%
6.50%
1
Notes: For the Mkt Cap and Weight columns, the final row is the simple sum. For the Return and Beta columns, the final row is the weighted average.
As alluded to earlier, some practitioners find that the reverse-optimization process leads to a nice starting point, but they often have alternative forecasts or views regarding the expected return of one or more of the asset classes that differ from the returns implied by reverse optimization based on market-capitalization weights. One example of having views that differ from the reverse-optimized returns has already been illustrated, when we altered the returns of Asia Pacific ex Japan equities and Europe ex UK equities by approximately 50 bps. Unfortunately, due to the sensitivity of mean–variance optimization to small changes in inputs, directly altering the expected returns caused relatively extreme and unintuitive changes in the resulting asset allocations. If one has strong views on expected returns that differ from the reverse-optimized returns, an alternative or additional approach is needed; the next section presents one alternative.
Black–Litterman Model
A complementary addition to reverse optimization is the Black–Litterman model, created by Fischer Black and Robert Litterman (see Black and Litterman 1990, 1991, 1992). Although the Black–Litterman model is often characterized as an asset allocation model, it is really a model for deriving a set of expected returns that can be used in an unconstrained or constrained optimization setting. The Black–Litterman model starts with excess returns (in excess of the risk-free rate) produced from reverse optimization and then provides a technique for altering reverse-optimized expected returns in such a way that they reflect an investor’s own distinctive views yet still behave well in an optimizer.
The Black–Litterman model has helped make the mean–variance optimization framework more useful. It enables investors to combine their unique forecasts of expected returns with reverse-optimized returns in an elegant manner. When coupled with a mean–variance or related framework, the resulting Black–Litterman expected returns often lead to well-diversified asset allocations by improving the consistency between each asset class’s expected return and its contribution to systematic risk. These asset allocations are grounded in economic reality—via the market capitalization of the assets typically used in the reverse-optimization process—but still reflect the information contained in the investor’s unique forecasts (or views) of expected return.
The mathematical details of the Black–Litterman model are beyond the scope of this reading, but many practitioners have access to asset allocation software that includes the Black–Litterman model.12 To assist with an intuitive understanding of the model and to show the model’s ability to blend new information (views) with reverse-optimized returns, we present an example based on the earlier views regarding the expected returns of Asia Pacific ex Japan equities and Europe ex UK equities. The Black–Litterman model has two methods for accepting views: one in which an absolute return forecast is associated with a given asset class and one in which the return differential of an asset (or group of assets) is expressed relative to another asset (or group of assets). Using the relative view format of the Black–Litterman model, we expressed the view that we believe Asia Pacific ex Japan equities will outperform Europe ex UK equities by 100 bps. We placed this view into the Black–Litterman model, which blends reverse-optimized returns with such views to create a new, mixed estimate.
Exhibit 13:
Comparison of Black–Litterman and Reverse-Optimized Returns
Asset Class
Reverse-Optimized Returns
Black–Litterman Returns
Difference
UK large cap
6.62%
6.60%
−0.02%
UK mid cap
6.92
6.87
−0.05
UK small cap
7.08
7.03
−0.05
US equities
7.81
7.76
−0.05
Europe ex UK equities
8.62
8.44
−0.18
Asia Pacific ex Japan equities
8.53
8.90
0.37
Japan equities
6.39
6.37
−0.02
Emerging market equities
8.96
9.30
0.33
Global REITs
9.02
9.00
−0.01
Global ex UK bonds
4.03
4.00
−0.03
UK bonds
2.94
2.95
0.01
Cash
2.50
2.50
0.00
Exhibit 14:
Efficient Frontier Asset Allocation Area Graph, Black–Litterman Returns
Exhibit 15:
Comparison of Select Efficient Asset Allocations, Black–Litterman Allocations vs. Base-Case Allocations
Modified 25/75
Base Case 25/75
Difference
Modified 50/50
Base Case 50/50
Difference
Modified 75/25
Base Case 75/25
Difference
UK large cap
0.4%
1.2%
−0.8%
1.4%
2.5%
−1.1%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
UK mid cap
0.4
0.6
−0.2
0.5
0.8
−0.3
0.0
0.0
0.0
UK small cap
0.4
0.5
−0.1
0.2
0.4
−0.2
0.0
0.0
0.0
US equities
13.8
13.8
0.0
26.8
26.8
0.0
40.0
40.5
−0.5
Europe ex UK equities
0.0
2.7
−2.7
0.0
6.5
−6.5
0.0
13.2
−13.2
Asia Pacific ex Japan equities
5.2
1.0
4.2
10.8
2.3
8.5
15.4
1.5
14.0
Japan equities
2.2
2.3
0.0
4.5
4.5
0.0
4.2
4.3
−0.1
Emerging market equities
1.8
2.0
−0.1
4.6
4.9
−0.2
9.8
10.0
−0.1
Global REITs
0.8
0.9
−0.1
1.3
1.4
−0.2
5.5
5.6
−0.1
Global ex UK bonds
10.3
10.6
−0.2
23.6
23.9
−0.3
25.0
25.0
0.0
UK bonds
3.1
2.7
0.3
3.5
3.0
0.5
0.0
0.0
0.0
Cash
61.6
61.7
−0.1
22.9
23.1
−0.1
0.0
0.0
0.0
Subtotal equities
25.0%
25.0%
50.0%
50.0%
75.0%
75.0%
Subtotal fixed income
75.0%
75.0%
50.0%
50.0%
25.0%
25.0%
Looking back at our original asset allocation area graph (), the reason for the well-behaved and well-diversified asset allocation mixes is now clear. By using reverse optimization, we are consistently relating assets’ expected returns to their systematic risk. If there isn’t a consistent relationship between the expected return and systematic risk, the optimizer will see this inconsistency as an opportunity and seek to take advantage of the more attractive attributes. This effect was clearly visible in our second asset allocation area graph after we altered the expected returns of Asia Pacific ex Japan equities and Europe ex UK equities.
compares the Black–Litterman model returns to the original reverse-optimized returns (as in but showing returns to the second decimal place based on calculations with full precision). The model accounts for the correlations of the assets with each other, and as one might expect, all of the returns change slightly (the change in return on cash was extremely small).
Next, we created another efficient frontier asset allocation area graph based on these new returns from the Black–Litterman model, as shown in . The allocations look relatively similar to those depicted in . However, if you compare the allocations to Asia Pacific ex Japan equities and Europe ex UK equities to their allocations in the original efficient frontier asset allocation graph, you will notice that allocations to Asia Pacific ex Japan equities have increased across the frontier and allocations to Europe ex UK equities have decreased across the frontier with very little impact on the other asset allocations.
As before, to aid in the comparison of (Black–Litterman allocations) with (the base-case allocations), we identified three specific mixes in and compared those efficient asset allocation mixes based on the expected returns from the Black–Litterman model to those of the base case. The results are shown in .